The length of the workweek

Table of contents

Child pages

The short answer

  • It looks like the answer is, "It depends".
    • In some industries people really only work about 20 hours out of their 40-hour-workweek, but they need to be there the full 40-hours in case something comes up. So depending on your definition of a "20 hour workweek", this may or may not qualify.
      People work for companies or customers (if they're self-employed), and the needs of those companies / customers can restrict the lifestyle of the worker.
      • For example, if someone works for a company which is in a battle-to-the-death with another company for a particular market, the survival of the company may depend on how quickly it can get certain things done; this will in turn depend on how many hours its employees work. So the employees may be compelled to work longer hours by the unavoidable competition that the company they work for faces. When I say "unavoidable competition", I mean that it seems that as long as competition exists between companies, this problem will remain.
      • As another example, if someone is self-employed and has customers, they may be competing with other self-employed people for the customer's business (like on Amazon's marketplace for used goods). Those self-employed people can "bid" for the customer's business by promising to do a better job (ie invest more time into the work) or by promising to get the work done faster (ie work a longer workweek).
    • Another thing to consider is that some people are able to work for a year or two in some lucrative job and then not work for a year or more afterwards. Similarly, some people are able to work in a lucrative job and then retire relatively early (in their 30s or 40s). So that's another sense in which the total number of hours worked by a person over their lifetime may go down without necessarily decreasing the person's workweek while they're working (ie they may work 80 hours / week while they're working, but over the total span of the "normal" working years (22-65) the total hours worked divided by the total weeks lived may lead to an average of lower than 40 hours, since the person was able to retire early).
  • Sites with good information:

How much have people worked at different points in the past?

  • 1968 - Man's Rise to Civilization As Shown by the Indians of North America from Primeval Times to the Coming of the Industrial State (via Wikipedia)
    • http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Working_time
      • Most people assume that the members of the Shoshone band worked ceaselessly in an unremitting search for sustenance. Such a dramatic picture might appear confirmed by an erroneous theory almost everyone recalls from schooldays: A high culture emerges only when the people have the leisure to build pyramids or to create art. The fact is that high civilization is hectic, and that primitive hunters and collectors of wild food, like the Shoshone, are among the most leisured people on earth. [Nathan - This matches up with what I remember reading in that book about life on some remote Pacific island.]
  • 1974 - Man in Adaptation: the cultural present (via Wikipedia)
    • http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Working_time
      • In all, the adults of the Dobe camp worked about two and a half days a week. Because the average working day was about six hours long, the fact emerges that !Kung Bushmen of Dobe, despite their harsh environment, devote from twelve to nineteen hours a week to getting food. Even the hardest working individual in the camp, a man named =oma who went out hunting on sixteen of the 28 days, spent a maximum of 32 hours a week in the food quest.
  • Hours of Work in the US from the 1800s to the 1950s
    • In the 1800s, many Americans worked seventy hours or more per week and the length of the workweek became an important political issue. Since then the workweek's length has decreased considerably. This article presents estimates of the length of the historical workweek in the U.S., describes the history of the shorter-hours "movement," and examines the forces that drove the workweek's decline over time.
      [...]
      It seems reasonable to accept two important conclusions based on these data [NW - see below] -- the length of the typical manufacturing workweek in the 1800s was very long by modern standards and it declined significantly between 1830 and 1890.

      Table 1
      Estimated Average Weekly Hours Worked in Manufacturing, 1830-1890

      Year - Weeks Report - Aldrich Report
      1830 - 69.1 - X
      1840 - 67.1 - 68.4
      1850 - 65.5 - 69.0
      1860 - 62.0 - 66.0
      1870 - 61.1 - 63.0
      1880 - 60.7 - 61.8
      1890 - X - 60.0

      [...]
      Hours of Work during the Twentieth Century
      [T]here is a fairly consistent pattern, with weekly hours falling considerably during the first third of the century and much more slowly thereafter. In particular, hours fell strongly during the years surrounding World War I, so that by 1919 the eight-hour day (with six workdays per week) had been won. Hours fell sharply at the beginning of the Great Depression, especially in manufacturing, then rebounded somewhat and peaked during World War II. After World War II, the length of the workweek stabilized around forty hours. Owen's nonstudent-male series shows little trend after World War II, but the other series show a slow, but steady, decline in the length of the average workweek.
      [...]
      Broader Trends in Time Use, 1880 to 2040
      In 1880 a typical male household head had very little leisure time -- only about 1.8 hours per day over the course of a year. However, as Fogel's (2000) estimates in Table 5 show, between 1880 and 1995 the amount of work per day fell nearly in half, allowing leisure time to more than triple. Because of the decline in the length of the workweek and the declining portion of a lifetime that is spent in paid work (due largely to lengthening periods of education and retirement) the fraction of the typical American's lifetime devoted to work has become remarkably small. Based on these trends Fogel estimates that four decades from now less than one-fourth of our discretionary time (time not needed for sleep, meals, and hygiene) will be devoted to paid work -- over three-fourths will be available for doing what we wish.
      [...]
      Causes of the Decline in the Length of the Workweek
      Supply, Demand and Hours of Work
      The length of the workweek, like other labor market outcomes, is determined by the interaction of the supply and demand for labor. Employers are torn by conflicting pressures. Holding everything else constant, they would like employees to work long hours because this means that they can utilize their equipment more fully and offset any fixed costs from hiring each worker (such as the cost of health insurance -- common today, but not a consideration a century ago). On the other hand, longer hours can bring reduced productivity due to worker fatigue and can bring worker demands for higher hourly wages to compensate for putting in long hours. If they set the workweek too high, workers may quit and few workers will be willing to work for them at a competitive wage rate. Thus, workers implicitly choose among a variety of jobs -- some offering shorter hours and lower earnings, others offering longer hours and higher earnings.

      Economic Growth and the Long-Term Reduction of Work Hours
      Historically employers and employees often agreed on very long workweeks because the economy was not very productive (by today's standards) and people had to work long hours to earn enough money to feed, clothe and house their families. The long-term decline in the length of the workweek, in this view, has primarily been due to increased economic productivity, which has yielded higher wages for workers. Workers responded to this rise in potential income by "buying" more leisure time, as well as by buying more goods and services. In a recent survey, a sizeable majority of economic historians agreed with this view. Over eighty percent accepted the proposition that "the reduction in the length of the workweek in American manufacturing before the Great Depression was primarily due to economic growth and the increased wages it brought" (Whaples, 1995). Other broad forces probably played only a secondary role. For example, roughly two-thirds of economic historians surveyed rejected the proposition that the efforts of labor unions were the primary cause of the drop in work hours before the Great Depression.
      [...]
      Cross-sectional Patterns from 1919
      In 1919 the average workweek varied tremendously, emphasizing the point that not all workers desired the same workweek. The workweek exceeded 69 hours in the iron blast furnace, cottonseed oil, and sugar beet industries, but fell below 45 hours in industries such as hats and caps, fur goods, and women's clothing. Cities' averages also differed dramatically. In a few Midwestern steel mill towns average workweeks exceeded 60 hours. In a wide range of low-wage Southern cities they reached the high 50s, but in high-wage Western ports, like Seattle, the workweek fell below 45 hours.

      Whaples (1990a) finds that among the most important city-level determinants of the workweek during this period were the availability of a pool of agricultural workers, the capital-labor ratio, horsepower per worker, and the amount of employment in large establishments. Hours rose as each of these increased. Eastern European immigrants worked significantly longer than others, as did people in industries whose output varied considerably from season to season. 
      [...]
      Economists have given surprisingly little attention to the determinants of the workweek. The most comprehensive treatment is Robert Whaples' "The Shortening of the American Work Week" (1990), which surveys estimates of the length of the workweek, the shorter hours movement, and economic theories about the length of the workweek.

  • 1999 - The Worst Mistake in the History of the Human Race
    • How do you show that the lives of people 10,000 years ago got better when they abandoned hunting and gathering for farming? Until recently, archaeologists had to resort to indirect tests, whose results (surprisingly) failed to support the progressivist view. Here's one example of an indirect test: Are twentieth century hunter-gatherers really worse off than farmers? Scattered throughout the world, several dozen groups of so-called primitive people, like the Kalahari bushmen, continue to support themselves that way. It turns out that these people have plenty of leisure time, sleep a good deal, and work less hard than their farming neighbors. For instance, the average time devoted each week to obtaining food is only 12 to 19 hours for one group of Bushmen, 14 hours or less for the Hadza nomads of Tanzania. One Bushman, when asked why he hadn't emulated neighboring tribes by adopting agriculture, replied, "Why should we, when there are so many mongongo nuts in the world?"

      While farmers concentrate on high-carbohydrate crops like rice and potatoes, the mix of wild plants and animals in the diets of surviving hunter-gatherers provides more protein and a bettter balance of other nutrients. In one study, the Bushmen's average daily food intake (during a month when food was plentiful) was 2,140 calories and 93 grams of protein, considerably greater than the recommended daily allowance for people of their size. It's almost inconceivable that Bushmen, who eat 75 or so wild plants, could die of starvation the way hundreds of thousands of Irish farmers and their families did during the potato famine of the 1840s.

  • http://www.billshrink.com/blog/4724/wor ... the-world/
  • Productivity and the Workweek
  • http://groups.csail.mit.edu/mac/users/rauch/worktime/
  • http://www.gobankingrates.com/history-o ... e-economy/
  • https://ooomf.com/blog/why-you-shouldnt-work-set-hours/
  • http://boingboing.net/2013/10/21/40-hou ... ol-of.html
  • http://www.telegraph.co.uk/finance/jobs ... mists.html
  • http://www.freedomlovin.com/4-reasons-w ... s-bullsht/
  • http://c2.com/cgi/wiki?FortyHourWeekHistory
  • http://www.quora.com/How-did-the-USA-ev ... -work-week
  • http://www.quora.com/Work/Who-invented- ... y-accepted
  • http://www.quora.com/Future-of-Work/How ... dern-world
  • Aeon magazine - John Quiggin - The golden age
    • The 15-hour working week predicted by Keynes may soon be within our grasp – but are we ready for freedom from toil?
  • Oxford - Karl Widerquist - An Introduction to Keynes’s “Economic Possibilities for Our Grandchildren”

Misc Articles

  • 1999.05.01 - The Worst Mistake in the History of the Human Race
    • Are twentieth century hunter-gatherers really worse off than farmers? Scattered throughout the world, several dozen groups of so-called primitive people, like the Kalahari bushmen, continue to support themselves that way. It turns out that these people have plenty of leisure time, sleep a good deal, and work less hard than their farming neighbors. For instance, the average time devoted each week to obtaining food is only 12 to 19 hours for one group of Bushmen, 14 hours or less for the Hadza nomads of Tanzania. One Bushman, when asked why he hadn't emulated neighboring tribes by adopting agriculture, replied, "Why should we, when there are so many mongongo nuts in the world?" [NW - but how many hours do they spend doing chores other than looking for food?]
      [...]
      The evidence suggests that the Indians at Dickson Mounds, like many other primitive peoples, took up farming not by choice but from necessity in order to feed their constantly growing numbers. [NW - So the same pressure might be increasing the number of hours people need to work nowadays.]
  • Book: How Much Is Enough? Money and the Good Life
    • The authors begin with the great economist John Maynard Keynes. In 1930 Keynes predicted that, within a century, per capita income would steadily rise, people’s basic needs would be met, and no one would have to work more than fifteen hours a week. Clearly, he was wrong: though income has increased as he envisioned, our wants have seemingly gone unsatisfied, and we continue to work long hours. The Skidelskys explain why Keynes was mistaken.
  • 2008.09.01 - The Guardian - Whatever happened to Keynes' 15-hour working week?
    • Gary Becker says Keynes based his predictions on the behaviour of the rich gentry of Britain, who tended to hold their wealth in the form of land, property or financial assets. When the value of these assets rose, they could earn the same income by working less hard. Wealth creation in the modern world, by contrast, has more to do with the use of human capital, and there is a price - lower earnings - when that human capital is left idle. Becker says that rich individuals in the Gulf states, who live off revenues from oil, are the only group that conforms to Keynes's ideal of a 15-hour working week.

      Robert Frank's explanation is that Keynes failed to spot the importance of context. We consume more because technical progress has vastly improved the quality of goods on offer, and as we get richer we want the luxury car with the satnav or the meal cooked by Gordon Ramsay.Contrary to belief, Frank says, those on middle and low incomes are not influenced greatly by what the super-rich get up to. Instead, they tend to measure themselves against people in their own peer group.
      [...]
      A greater degree of income equality would help, for two reasons.

      Firstly, there is evidence that those on low pay have no choice but to work long hours. In his essay, Richard Freeman notes that more Americans than Europeans say that they want to increase hours worked than to decrease at given wage rates, and that's probably a function of a lower minimum wage and stagnant real incomes for all but the highest earners.

      The second reason is that the widening earnings gap creates an incentive to put in longer hours, since the rewards for doing so are considerable. [NW - In other words, the marginal benefit of each extra hour worked is higher when there is a lot of income inequality, and lower when there isn't a lot of income inequality. That's an interesting observation that I hadn't thought about.]

  • 2012.02.10 - Save the world with a 3-day work week
    • This article is reporting on the paper released by the New Economics Foundation
    • Ms. Coote says her foundation is not promoting a mandatory approach by government, but prefers cultural change. You may gasp at a 21-hour work week today – or even a 30-hour week – but you may have been equally unbelieving in the past that smoking could be curtailed, seat belt restraints and cycling helmets become common, and voluntary recycling become widespread. “We want to influence the climate of opinion and then change thinking. If in time we need a regulatory underpinning, that can be done, but first we need a change in attitudes,” she says.

      The report notes that the Factory Acts at the end of the 19th century first limited the paid working week and by the beginning of the Second World War the eight-hour day and the five-day week were beginning to be seen as normal. “Fewer workers clock in and out of their jobs these days, but the logic of industrial time still ticks away in our heads, shaping how we understand our lives,” the researchers state.

  • 2013.05.19 - WonkBlog (Ezra Klein) - Keynes was, incredibly, right about the future. He was wrong about how we’d be spending it.
  • 2013.06.13 - How Much Is Enough? Why Do We Work So Much and Enjoy So Little Leisure? ← really good article
    • As the Skidelskys note, we are pretty nearly on target for the standard of living that Keynes forecast, yet, they say, he was mistaken about the amount of work. “The central puzzle remains: we in the rich world are four or five times better off on average than we were in 1930, but our average hours of work have fallen only a fifth since then.” They supported this passage with a chart showing that weekly hours worked, which, by Keynes’ estimate, should have fallen from fifty to about eighteen by now, are still stuck at forty.
      The Skidelskys review three possible explanations:
      First, that people take joy in their work. They find that plausible for artists, skilled artisans, and authors but not for most people.
      Second, that the capitalist system forces people to work because employers, not workers, get to call the tune. They approvingly quote sociological theories supporting that view, but in the end, they do not find it entirely persuasive.
      Third, that wants are insatiable. Although that sometimes seems to be the case, they think that insatiability is not a fixed feature of human nature, but a flaw of our economic system. Keynes, they say, “did not understand that capitalism would set up a new dynamic of want creation that would overwhelm traditional restraints of custom and good sense. . . . Capitalism has achieved incomparable progress in the creation of wealth , but has left us incapable of putting that wealth to civilized use.”
  • 2013.08.17 - Strike Mag - On the Phenomenon of Bullshit Jobs
    • YC comments: https://news.ycombinator.com/item?id=8561080
    • This guy is clueless.
    • But rather than allowing a massive reduction of working hours to free the world’s population to pursue their own projects, pleasures, visions, and ideas, we have seen the ballooning not even so much of the “service” sector as of the administrative sector, up to and including the creation of whole new industries like financial services or telemarketing, or the unprecedented expansion of sectors like corporate law, academic and health administration, human resources, and public relations. And these numbers do not even reflect on all those people whose job is to provide administrative, technical, or security support for these industries, or for that matter the whole host of ancillary industries (dog-washers, all-night pizza deliverymen) that only exist because everyone else is spending so much of their time working in all the other ones.

      These are what I propose to call “bullshit jobs.”

      [NW: I disagree. See my comment for the next paragraph.]

      (...)

      While corporations may engage in ruthless downsizing, the layoffs and speed-ups invariably fall on that class of people who are actually making, moving, fixing and maintaining things; through some strange alchemy no one can quite explain, the number of salaried paper-pushers ultimately seems to expand, and more and more employees find themselves, not unlike Soviet workers actually, working 40 or even 50 hour weeks on paper, but effectively working 15 hours just as Keynes predicted, since the rest of their time is spent organizing or attending motivational seminars, updating their facebook profiles or downloading TV box-sets.

      [NW response: It isn't strange alchemy; it's just the scaling-up of systems to benefit from economies of scale and the continued division of labor. For example, in a village you might have one person making hammers for the entire village; the hammers may not be very good but he will be able to easily see how his efforts benefit others. In the 21st century global marketplace you might have a multinational corporation doing that job, and because of the division of labor and economies of scale they can provide hammers which are 1,000x better and 100x cheaper. But to do that you need to have an army of people, where each person is doing a very small piece of the entire process. So to each person it may seem like their contribution isn't important, and it may very well be the case that some of them are working on things that won't end up contributing to the final product, but if you understand the big picture you can see how seemingly-unimportant jobs can actually be very important.]

      (...)

      in our society, there seems a general rule that, the more obviously one’s work benefits other people, the less one is likely to be paid for it. Again, an objective measure is hard to find, but one easy way to get a sense is to ask: what would happen were this entire class of people to simply disappear? Say what you like about nurses, garbage collectors, or mechanics, it’s obvious that were they to vanish in a puff of smoke, the results would be immediate and catastrophic. A world without teachers or dock-workers would soon be in trouble, and even one without science fiction writers or ska musicians would clearly be a lesser place. It’s not entirely clear how humanity would suffer were all private equity CEOs, lobbyists, PR researchers, actuaries, telemarketers, bailiffs or legal consultants to similarly vanish. (Many suspect it might markedly improve.) Yet apart from a handful of well-touted exceptions (doctors), the rule holds surprisingly well.

      [NW response: This is the "paradox of value", something discussed by many intellectuals, including Adam Smith.]

  • 2013.08.29 - Reuters - Why a medieval peasant got more vacation time than you
  • 2013 - Eureka! The shorter workweek is here!
    • I did not realize this until a friend told me that the Obamacare law requires businesses employing 50 or more workers to provide health-care coverage if these employees average 30 or more hours a week. (See 26 USC § 4980 H.) A fine is imposed if the employer fails to provide such coverage. This is an incentive for employers to reduce working hours in order to avoid the cost of the coverage or the cost of the fines.

      The reality of this new requirement came home when a tenant in a duplex I own told me that she was looking for a second job to make ends meet. She manages a pizza delivery operation in a Minneapolis suburb. Her hours were being cut to below 30 hours per week, with a commensurate reduction in pay. To make up for the lost pay, she was looking for a part-time position with a similar business in another suburb. I understood that she would be working at least one fewer day in the week; and she would use that day to work at the second business establishment.

      What to make of this? The woman was not happy about the change but was taking it in stride. The bottom-line reality was that she would not receive health-care coverage in either job and, presumably, would be earning about the same amount of money, though from two different employers.

      As a long-time advocate of shorter working hours, I see a silver lining. I have long thought that the U.S. Government might amend the Fair Labor Standards Act to create a 32-hour standard workweek. This would bring weekly work time down to 32 hours from 40 or more, producing many new jobs. Now, it seems, we have a federally mandated 30-hour workweek (same as what would have happened if the Black-Connery Act of 1933 had been signed into law) under the back door of health-care reform.

Length of the workweek